
An official website of the United States government
I appreciate the opportunity to testify today in response to the Subcommittees questions about the actions the Bureau of
Labor Statistics (BLS) has taken and will be taking to improve the accuracy of the Consumer Price Index (CPI). To provide
some context for the activities I will describe this morning, I also will discuss some of the measurement issues raised in the
December 1996 report of the Senate Finance Committees Advisory Commission to Study the Consumer Price Index.
It is important to note at the outset that the BLS has a long tradition of being in the forefront of price measurement research
and operational innovation. Attached to my statement is a document listing many of the improvements to the procedures used
in constructing the CPI that the BLS has made over the years (Attachment A). I would particularly draw the Subcommittees
attention to those improvements introduced over just the past two years, including steps taken in 1995 and 1996 to identify
and resolve the so-called "formula bias" problem, and the introduction earlier this year of a new approach to the measurement
of prices for hospital services. These refinements are indicative of the Bureaus ongoing commitment to keeping its measures
as accurate and up-to-date as possible.
The Bureau, in fact, has efforts currently underway and future activities planned that will further improve the accuracy of the
index. Just this month we have begun issuing a new experimental measure that is designed to help us in identifying the best way
to address the so-called "lower-level" substitution bias in the CPI (which I will describe at greater length a bit later in my
testimony). I also am pleased that the Presidents Fiscal Year (FY) 1998 budget includes a program increment that will allow
us to take several additional steps toward increasing the accuracy of the CPI. The BLS will be requesting resources to speed
up the process of updating the CPI market basket in future revisions. Resources to expand the collection of information on the
prices and characteristics of certain goods and services, together with resources to be devoted to the early identification of
new goods as they become available in the marketplace, also will be requested. This information will enable us to improve the
methods we use to adjust for quality change and to insure that new items are brought into the index in a more timely fashion.
Finally, the request provides for the production of supplementary measures of change in consumer prices that we believe
would provide closer approximations to the change in the cost of living than the currently published CPI. At the appropriate
points in my testimony, I will indicate the relationship between these current and planned activities and the issues raised in the
Commissions report.
The Advisory Commissions report begins with one overarching recommendation: "The BLS should establish a cost of living
index (COLI) as its objective in measuring consumer prices." This seems basically right to me. Indeed, the BLS long has said
that it operates within a cost-of-living framework in producing the CPI. That framework has guided, and will continue to
guide, operational decisions about the construction of the index. Putting things slightly differently, if the BLS staff or other
technical experts knew how to produce a true cost of living index on a monthly production schedule, that would be what we
would produce. I therefore have no fundamental disagreement with the Commission about what the objective of our CPI
program ought to be, though we disagree to some extent about what changes to the index would be feasible and prudent and
about the timetable on which those changes could be implemented.
More specifically, the Commissions report focuses on two broad issues concerning the CPI as a proxy measuring changes in
the cost of living of the U.S. consumer. The first is substitution bias, comprising what the Commission terms lower-level and
upper-level components. The Commission believes that these components together impart an upward bias in the CPI of 0.4
percentage point per year. The second broad issue involves how best to treat changes in the quality of goods and services that
consumers buy, changes in how and where those goods and services are sold, and the emergence of new goods and services.
The Commission believes that failure to adjust adequately for these effects imparts a 0.7 percentage point per year upward
bias to the CPI. The total overstatement of the change in the cost of living due to substitution bias and other problems together
is judged by the Commission to amount to 1.1 percentage points per year.
Let me talk first about substitution bias. Like the Commission members, I also am an economist. Almost any economist would
agree that an index such as the CPI that tracks the cost of purchasing a fixed market basket of goods and services represents
an upper bound on the change in the cost of living. Indeed, for many years, the BLS has attempted to explain exactly this
point.
Operationally, as the Commission suggests, substitution bias may show up at two levels. By way of background, the CPI is
constructed by first aggregating the roughly 90,000 price quotations collected each month to form a series of subindexes for
categories of items such as "Apples," "Mens Shirts," and "Prescription Drugs," and then aggregating those subindexes to form
the overall CPI. The formula used to aggregate the individual price quotations to form the subindexes does not account for
consumers ability to substitute across items within item categories when the relative prices of those items change - for
example, when the price of Delicious apples increases and the price of Granny Smith apples falls. Similarly, the formula used
to aggregate the subindexes to form the overall CPI does not reflect the substitution across item categories that takes place
when the relative prices of items in different categories change - for example, when the price of apples falls relative to the price
of oranges. Were such substitution taken into account, the CPI undoubtedly would rise less rapidly.
To address the so-called lower-level substitution problem, the Commission has suggested adoption of an alternative formula
for aggregating price quotations, one that has been under investigation by the BLS over the past several years. As noted
above, the current CPI formula does not allow for the potential substitution among items within a category, such as between
different varieties of apples, when the relative prices of those items change. The proposed alternative formula, termed the
geometric mean formula, is based on a different assumption about consumers substitution behavior, namely that consumers
substitute among items in such a way as to hold the share of their expenditures devoted to each item constant. Neither the
assumption of no substitution underlying our current practice nor the assumption underlying the geometric mean formula is
likely to provide a close approximation in all cases. It may be more plausible to assume that consumers substitute freely
between types of apples or between brands of television sets when their relative prices change than to assume similar
substitutability between types of prescription drugs or between electric power companies in an area. As I indicated earlier, the
BLS has begun issuing a monthly experimental measure that is constructed using the geometric mean formula in all index
components, and will make a decision by the end of this year as to which components of the official CPI should employ the
geometric mean formula..
Upper-level substitution bias occurs because the formula currently used to aggregate CPI subindexes ignores the fact that
consumers substitute across item categories when relative prices change. Here, however, the nature of the operational
problem faced by the BLS is a bit different than that at the lower level of item aggregation. The detailed data needed to
account for lower-level substitution in the calculation of CPI subindexes are simply not available. In contrast, at the upper level
of item aggregation, the BLS does collect information on consumer expenditures across item categories, like apples, mens
shirts, and prescription drugs. Therefore, it is possible to construct a measure that accounts for substitution across those item
categories in response to relative price changes, though not on the same schedule as the current CPI. The expenditure
information required to construct such a measure -- one of the so-called superlative indexes -- is available only with a lag, so
that the index cannot be produced until the fall following the year to which it applies. The BLS currently produces these
measures on an experimental basis, and would be happy to produce them to a higher standard of precision and reliability.
Thus, we are receptive to the spirit of the Commissions recommendation that we produce an annual superlative index as a
supplement to the official monthly CPI, and will be able to make substantial headway in this regard if we receive the FY 1998
program increase we are requesting.
Recognizing the unavoidable time lag in producing a true superlative measure, the Commission recommends that the BLS
explore steps that might make the monthly CPI a better approximation to such an index. The Commission has suggested, for
example, that updating the indexs expenditure weights on a continuous rather than a periodic basis and changing the formula
for aggregating subindexes might make the CPI behave more like a superlative index. The BLS is, of course, open to
exploring this sort of option, as can be seen in the variety of experimental indexes we have published for some time, and we
will continue our work in this area. Adopting any option that has neither a sound theoretical foundation nor a clear empirical
justification, however, would be a mistake. We can produce superlative measures, albeit with a lag, and thus convincingly deal
with the "substitution bias" problem. I believe we would gain little, and possibly do much damage to the credibility of our
statistical system, if we were to move hastily to adopt untested techniques for producing the official CPI.
Because it has received so much attention, I have spent a good deal of time talking about substitution bias. The largest share
of the bias in the CPI that the Commission concludes exists -- 0.7 percentage point per year, or nearly two-thirds of the total
of 1.1 percentage points per year -- arises from other sources. The Commission believes that the failure to make adequate
adjustment for changes in the quality of the goods and services people buy and to account properly for the value to consumers
of newly available goods, together with deficiencies in the way the CPI treats differences in the prices charged at different
retail outlets, constitute a serious problem.
Before commenting on the evidence marshaled by the Commission in support of its conclusions in the quality/new goods area,
I would like to note that the BLS already has procedures in place designed to account for changes in the quality of the items
being priced. (It often mistakenly has been assumed, though not by the Commission, that BLS makes few or no such
adjustments.) Although I would readily acknowledge that our adjustment procedures are not perfect, they do have a very
important effect on the rate of price change the BLS reports. The best available information on this point applies to a CPI
subindex covering roughly the commodities and services component of the market basket (about 70 percent of the total, with
shelter the largest exclusion). During 1995, this subindex would have risen by 3.9 percentage points had these procedures not
been applied. Because of their application, however, the subindex actually rose by only 2.2 percentage points over the year.
Roughly speaking, these figures imply that the adjustments made by the BLS for changes in the quality of these goods and
services amounted to 1.7 percentage points over the course of a single year. (These figures are somewhat different from those
I reported in other testimony earlier this year. We have refined our prior estimates principally to exclude some "quality
adjustments" that are made to account for changes in units of measurement or package size that might not normally be thought
of as quality change.) I would add that the BLS also has established procedures for bringing new items and new outlets into
the index. The expenditure share information used to aggregate the CPI subindexes is updated only once every ten years or
so, but the specific stores in which prices are collected and the specific items priced are reselected on a five-year cycle.
Although more frequent sample rotations undoubtedly would be desirable, it is a fact that a considerable share of the
resources available for producing the CPI are devoted to ensuring that the sample of items priced is representative of what
consumers actually are purchasing.
The Commission does not argue, of course, that the BLS is not making a good effort to address quality/new goods biases, but
rather that, in spite of a good effort, residual bias remains. The reports approach to assessing this residual bias is to divide the
index into 27 categories, and then to make a judgment about the magnitude of the bias in each case. Unfortunately, the
evidence applicable to many of these categories is rather sparse.
In some of the categories, absent evidence, the Commission is forced to fall back on its best judgment. The food and
beverages categories are perhaps the best examples; the Commissions estimates of upward biases in these categories rest
exclusively on not implausible, but unsubstantiated, judgments regarding the value to consumers of increased variety on
grocery and liquor store shelves, together with the value of greater choice in restaurants.
In other cases, members of the Commission have produced evidence that bears on the trend in prices for particular sorts of
items. I cannot say, however, that this evidence always leads me to the same conclusions as those reached by the
Commission. The Commissions estimate that the growth in prices of new and used cars has been overstated by 0.6
percentage point per year in the recent past, for example, rests on data showing that the average age of cars on the road has
risen, together with an assumption that current CPI procedures do not capture any of the increases in automobile durability
that may have occurred. This latter assumption, however, is incorrect; attached to my testimony is a document listing some of
the many durability-related model changes for which adjustments have been made in the CPI over the past few years
(Attachment B).
The Commissions estimate that the CPI has overstated the rate of growth of apparel prices by 1.0 percentage point per year
since 1985, to take another example, rests on a comparison of the official CPI data with price indexes constructed using
Sears catalogue prices for items remaining unchanged from one year to the next. Even beyond the reservations I have about
drawing any general conclusions based upon the prices charged by a single catalogue merchant, I am skeptical of any index
based only on the prices of unchanging items, particularly in a market segment where changing fashion is as important as it is in
apparel.
On another note, I also would have found the report more persuasive had the Commission made a more systematic effort to
explore the possible existence of negative biases in the CPI. Other analysts have hypothesized reduced convenience and
comfort of air travel, and deteriorating quality of higher education, as examples of quality decreases that are ignored in the
CPI. More generally, whereas the Commission notes some service quality improvements, such as the introduction of
automatic credit-card readers at gasoline pumps, the BLS often hears complaints about broad-ranging declines in the quality
of customer service, which are equally difficult to incorporate in the CPI.
A more subtle issue is that price increases for many goods occur intermittently and often are timed to coincide with model
replacements or other quality improvements. The BLS commonly adjusts for quality differences between successive models
by, in effect, treating the difference in price between them as wholly attributable to a difference in quality. There is a risk that
this procedure over-adjusts for quality change, imparting a downward bias to the index. Methods have been introduced to try
to minimize that possibility, but the Commission paid little attention to this potential problem.
Close to half of the quality/new goods bias the Commission believes exists in the overall CPI is judged to occur in just two
areas of the index: medical care and high-tech consumer goods. These clearly are components of the index in which the BLS
faces particularly difficult measurement problems, though I cannot say what the magnitude of any bias in these index
components might be.
From a BLS perspective, the most important question about possible quality/new goods problems is what we might do to
improve our procedures and ameliorate those problems. Recognizing the particular difficulties associated with measuring
medical care prices and high-tech consumer goods prices, the BLS has devised and announced important improvements in
our methods. These include changes in our hospital price measurement procedures, effective with the data for January of this
year, and prospective changes in our sample rotation procedures that will allow us to update item samples in rapidly changing
market segments more frequently than once every five years (at the cost of less frequent updates in more static market
segments). In addition, the FY 1998 budget we are submitting would allow us to make important progress in the quality/new
goods area, by supporting greater use of techniques that explicitly account for changes in the characteristics of items being
purchased and implementation of more aggressive procedures for identifying and beginning to price new goods promptly once
they appear in the marketplace.
The Commissions report also discusses the question of new outlet bias, namely, how changes in the mix of retail outlets at
which consumers shop ought to be treated. Current CPI procedures treat purchases of a particular item at different retail
outlets as distinct transactions; the prices at the different stores are never directly compared. This could impart an upward bias
to the CPI if, for example, stores offering lower prices but comparable service gained in market share. As a practical matter,
however, measurement of any such bias is complicated by the fact that different types of outlets commonly offer quite different
shopping environments. Research on the factors affecting consumers choices about where to shop ultimately may be helpful in
devising appropriate procedures for dealing with changes in outlet mix.
All of this, however, leaves us a long way from having a complete solution to the quality/new goods and new outlet problems
the Commission believes exist with the CPI. There is much of what the Commission discusses that we do not know how to
measure -- or, to put it another way, for which economists simply do not have operational procedures to correct the problems
cited. Let me try to illustrate what I mean.
Has the variety of goods and services available to consumers grown? I am certain that it has. Is this variety of value to
consumers? Again, I would answer yes. We are, however, a very long way from being able to measure the value of that
variety, and thus a very long way from being able to reflect the value of increased variety in the monthly CPI. We have been
actively working on potential uses for scanner data in the CPI, one of which might be to allow us to identify new product
introductions soon after they occur. Unfortunately, the techniques available for measuring the gains in consumer welfare from
those new products (and the losses from product disappearances) are in their infancy, and may never be adaptable for
implementation in a large, ongoing price measurement program like the CPI.
To take another example, I would readily acknowledge that there have been major improvements in the medical treatment
available for many serious health problems -- improvements that have been of indubitable value to those suffering from the
afflictions in question. Unfortunately, as a general matter, the BLS has no good way to measure the value of these
improvements. Consider, to take just one example, a hypothetical improvement in knee surgery techniques that gives patients
greater mobility following surgery than they previously could have expected. This improved mobility undoubtedly would be of
value to those who benefit from the improvement in technique, but there is no obvious or clearly objective way to quantify that
value. This is, I believe, an important point about which the Commission and the BLS are in agreement.
The BLS is committed to producing the very best CPI it can. Indeed, as Ive noted, our Fiscal Year 1998 budget request
proposes an increase in funding that would enable us to make significant progress on a number of the issues we have
discussed here today. Although I believe that we can make important improvements in the CPI, I do not believe it to be
possible to produce a perfect cost-of-living measure. This means that those who use the data we are able to produce should
recognize the limitations of those data and exercise judgment accordingly concerning whether and how the data ought to be
used.
Change | Date | Description |
---|---|---|
New Construction | 1966 |
Rent samples augmented with units built after 1960. |
Quality Adjustment of New Automobile Prices | 1967 |
New automobile prices adjusted for quality differences after model changeovers. |
Sample rotation | 1981 |
Introduced a systematic replacement of outlets between major revisions. |
Rental Equivalence | 1983 |
Changed homeowners' component from cost of purchase to value of rental services for CPI-U. |
Return from Sale Price Imputation | 1984 |
Introduced procedure to eliminate downward bias due to items discontinued by outlets that went out of index with discounted prices. |
Rental Equivalence | 1985 |
Changed homeowners' component to value of rental services for CPI-W. |
Enhanced Seasonal Products Methodology | 1987 |
Enhanced methodology used for seasonal items by expanding the number of price quotations to allow selection of products from alternate seasons and eliminate under-representation of such items. |
Quality Adjustment of Used Car Prices | 1987 |
Used car prices adjusted for differences in quality after model changeovers. |
Aging Bias Correction | 1988 |
Rental values adjusted for aging of the housing stock. |
Imputation Procedures for New Cars and Trucks | 1989 |
Price changes for non-comparable new models imputed using only the constant-quality price changes for comparable model changeovers. |
Quality Adjustment of Apparel Prices | 1991 |
Regression models used to adjust apparel prices for changes in quality when new clothing lines introduced and eliminate bias due to linking product substitutions into the CPI. |
Discount Air Fares | 1991 |
Substitution rules modified to expand pricing of discount airline fares. |
Sample Augmentation | 1992 |
Increased the number of outlets from which prices are collected to replace sample lost through sample attrition. |
New Models Imputation | 1992 |
Refined imputation methods used when introducing new sample items into the CPI. |
Hotels & Motels | 1992 |
Samples for hotels and motels quadrupled to reduce variances related to seasonal pricing. |
Seasonal Adjustment | 1994 |
Procedures for seasonal adjustment revised to eliminate residual seasonality effects. |
Quality Adjustment for Gasoline | 1994 |
Treated "reformulated" gasoline as a quality improvement and adjusted the price to reflect quality difference. Impact of the change estimated. |
Generic Drugs | 1995 |
Introduced new procedures which allow generic drugs to be priced when a brand drug loses its patent. |
Food at Home Base Period Prices | 1995 |
Introduced seasoning procedures to eliminate upward bias in setting of base period prices of newly initiated items. |
Rental Equivalence | 1995 |
Modified imputation of homeowners' implicit rent to eliminate the upward drift property of the current estimator. |
Composite Estimator Used in Housing | 1995 |
Replaced composite estimator with a six-month chain estimator. Under-reporting of one-month rent changes had resulted in missing price change in residential rent and home-owners' equivalent rent. Old estimator also produced higher variances. |
Commodities and Services Base Period Prices | 1996 |
Extended food-at-home seasoning procedures to remainder of commodities and services series. Base period prices left unchanged in most noncomparable substitutions. |
Hospital and Related Services | 1997 |
Reclassified item strata to better reflect shifts in patterns of treatment. Shifted to pricing services on selected patient bills to reflect alternative reimbursement methods and to improve quality adjustment. |
Attachment B: Examples Of New Car Reliability/Durability Quality Adjustments In The
CPI Since 1992